\documentclass[11pt]{article} \usepackage{geometry} % See geometry.pdf to learn the layout options. There are lots. \geometry{letterpaper} \setlength{\textwidth}{16cm} % \ldots or a4paper or a5paper or \ldots %\geometry{landscape} % Activate for for rotated page geometry \usepackage[parfill]{parskip} % Activate to begin paragraphs with an empty line rather than an indent \usepackage{graphicx} \usepackage{amssymb,amsmath} \usepackage{epstopdf} \DeclareGraphicsRule{.tif}{png}{.png}{`convert #1 `dirname #1`/`basename #1 .tif`.png} \begin{document} \begin{center} \Large How Much Money Could a Person Donate\\ by Having a Conventional Job?\\ \vspace{.2cm} \normalsize webmaster [``at"] utilitarian-essays.com\\ \vspace{.1cm} Last Update: 23 August 2007\\ \vspace{.4cm} \end{center} \begin{abstract} I examine how much donatable wealth someone could accumulate by taking a conventional job and investing his earnings. In current dollars, this figure ranges from just a few million dollars for most careers to around 30 or 60 million dollars. These figures assume a 12\% expected return on wealth, and (due to oversight on my part) ignore capital-gains tax. Other findings: \begin{itemize} \item It's better to save one's wealth and donate it all at the end of one's life than to give it away periodically. This is true even when we account for the fact that waiting longer increases the risk of losing everything. This conclusion may not apply, however, in cases where the causes to which one might donate have ``rates of return" of their own comparable to or higher than those of capital-market investments. \item For those with moderate to high annual incomes, the opportunity cost of exercise is more than paid back by the expectation of being able to work for a few more years as a result. \end{itemize} \end{abstract} \section{Introduction} Our hero Paul plans to take a conventional salary-paying job. He intends to live as frugally as possible and invest his earnings. Periodically, he will donate his money to reducing suffering. I do not claim that this is the best strategy Paul could adopt. Perhaps it would be better for Paul to become an entrepreneur, or to gain influence over funding and grantmaking, or to do something else entirely. In this essay, I merely consider how much donatable income Paul could make with this approach. \section{Model} \subsection{Without Inflation} First, imagine that there is no inflation. All money has units of current dollars. Divide time $t$ into years. Let $t=0$ represent the current year. Paul starts work at $t=0$ and gives away his money for the last time at $t=f$. Between now and $f$, Paul donates all of his current savings a total of $n$ equally spaced times. That is, he donates money at $t=\lfloor\frac{f}{n}\rfloor$, $\lfloor\frac{2f}{n}\rfloor$, \ldots, $\lfloor\frac{nf}{n}\rfloor=f$. ($\lfloor x\rfloor$ means ``the greatest integer less than $x$." I include this function merely to keep my values of $t$ integers.) To reduce clutter, I introduce the following notation: \begin{equation} \tau_k := \left\lfloor\frac{k f}{n}\right\rfloor. \end{equation} As a special case of this definition, $\tau_0 := -1$, not 0.\footnote{I do this so that the term $t=\tau_{k-1}+1$ for $k=1$ in \eqref{second} gives $t=0$ (the year when Paul starts working) instead of $t=1$.} Define $A(t)$ to be the amount of money that Paul accumulates by time $t$. Then Paul donates a total of $D$ dollars: \begin{equation}\label{first} D \equiv \sum_{k=1}^nA(\tau_k). \end{equation} At his job, Paul earns $I(t)$ dollars per year; he annually pays $T(t)$ dollars in income taxes and $C(t)$ dollars in living costs. (I define $C(t)$ to include property taxes, sales taxes, and other taxes that don't depend on income.) The remaining money, $I(t)-T(t)-C(t)$, Paul puts into aggressive-growth investment options,\footnote{See ``The Case for Risky Investments," (http://utilitarian-essays.com/risky-investments.html).} returning an annual interest rate $r$ (which I assume to be constant in time). Paul saves the money until $t=\tau_k$, when he gives it away for the $k$th time. If all goes well, Paul will give away \begin{equation}\label{second} A(\tau_k) = \sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)(1+r)^{\tau_k-t}. \end{equation} However, there's a nontrivial chance that all will not go well. For instance, the stock market might crash, or Paul might change his mind about giving away money and decide to keep it for himself. It's even somewhat likely that humanity will go extinct within the next few decades \cite{rees, existential, dodos, leslie}. Suppose there's some constant probability $p$ that one of these disasters will \textit{not} happen within one year. The probability that none of these disasters will have happened by $t=\tau_k$ is then $p^{\tau_k}$. The new, appropriately discounted form of $\eqref{second}$ is thus \begin{equation}\label{ssecond} A(\tau_k) = p^{\tau_k}\sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)(1+r)^{\tau_k-t}. \end{equation} Combining \eqref{first} and \eqref{ssecond}, \begin{equation}\label{four} D = \sum_{k=1}^np^{\tau_k} \left[ \sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)(1+r)^{\tau_k-t} \right]. \end{equation} \subsection{With Inflation} Now I modify \eqref{four} to account for inflation. Suppose inflation happens at constant rate of $i$ percent annually. By $t=\tau_k$, a dollar will be worth only $\frac{1}{(1+i)^{\tau_k}}$ as much as it is currently. So we should reexpress $D$ in terms of actual buying power: \begin{equation}\label{five} D = \sum_{k=1}^n\frac{p^{\tau_k}}{(1+i)^{\tau_k}} \left[ \sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)(1+r)^{\tau_k-t} \right]. \end{equation} Because we've adjusted for inflation, $D$ is still in current dollars. Of course, we also need to account for the effect of inflation on $I(t)$, $T(t)$, and $C(t)$. If we let those variables represent what income, taxes, and cost of living, respectively, would have been without inflation, and if we assume that those variables keep pace with inflation, then \eqref{five} becomes \begin{equation}\label{six} \begin{split} D =& \sum_{k=1}^n\frac{p^{\tau_k}}{(1+i)^{\tau_k}} \left[ \sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}(1+i)^t\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)(1+r)^{\tau_k-t} \right]\\ =&\sum_{k=1}^np^{\tau_k} \left[ \sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}(1+i)^{t-\tau_k}\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)(1+r)^{\tau_k-t} \right]\\ =&\sum_{k=1}^np^{\tau_k} \left[ \sum_{t=\tau_{k-1}+1}^{\tau_k}\Bigl(I(t)-T(t)-C(t)\Bigr)\Bigl(\frac{1+i}{1+r}\Bigr)^{t-\tau_k} \right].\\ \end{split} \end{equation} \subsection{Further Modifications} Assume $I(t)$ can be represented by a straight line. The line has slope $\frac{I(f)-I(0)}{f-0}$ and passes through $t=0$ at $I(0)$, so that \begin{equation}\label{i} I(t) = I(0) + \frac{I(f)-I(0)}{f}t. \end{equation} Assuming a constant tax rate, $T(t) = hI(t)$ for some $h$, $0